54. The Aiyagari Model#

54.1. Overview#

In this lecture we describe the structure of a class of models that build on work by Truman Bewley [Bew77].

We begin by discussing an example of a Bewley model due to Rao Aiyagari.

The model features

  • Heterogeneous agents.

  • A single exogenous vehicle for borrowing and lending.

  • Limits on amounts individual agents may borrow.

The Aiyagari model has been used to investigate many topics, including

  • precautionary savings and the effect of liquidity constraints [Aiy94]

  • risk sharing and asset pricing [HL96]

  • the shape of the wealth distribution [BBZ15]

  • etc., etc., etc.

54.1.1. References#

The primary reference for this lecture is [Aiy94].

A textbook treatment is available in chapter 18 of [LS18].

A continuous time version of the model by SeHyoun Ahn and Benjamin Moll can be found here.

54.2. The Economy#

54.2.1. Households#

Infinitely lived households / consumers face idiosyncratic income shocks.

A unit interval of ex ante identical households face a common borrowing constraint.

The savings problem faced by a typical household is

\[ \max \mathbb E \sum_{t=0}^{\infty} \beta^t u(c_t) \]

subject to

\[ a_{t+1} + c_t \leq w z_t + (1 + r) a_t \quad c_t \geq 0, \quad \text{and} \quad a_t \geq -B \]

where

  • \(c_t\) is current consumption

  • \(a_t\) is assets

  • \(z_t\) is an exogenous component of labor income capturing stochastic unemployment risk, etc.

  • \(w\) is a wage rate

  • \(r\) is a net interest rate

  • \(B\) is the maximum amount that the agent is allowed to borrow

The exogenous process \(\{z_t\}\) follows a finite state Markov chain with given stochastic matrix \(P\).

The wage and interest rate are fixed over time.

In this simple version of the model, households supply labor inelastically because they do not value leisure.

54.3. Firms#

Firms produce output by hiring capital and labor.

Firms act competitively and face constant returns to scale.

Since returns to scale are constant the number of firms does not matter.

Hence we can consider a single (but nonetheless competitive) representative firm.

The firm’s output is

\[ Y_t = A K_t^{\alpha} N^{1 - \alpha} \]

where

  • \(A\) and \(\alpha\) are parameters with \(A > 0\) and \(\alpha \in (0, 1)\)

  • \(K_t\) is aggregate capital

  • \(N\) is total labor supply (which is constant in this simple version of the model)

The firm’s problem is

\[ max_{K, N} \left\{ A K_t^{\alpha} N^{1 - \alpha} - (r + \delta) K - w N \right\} \]

The parameter \(\delta\) is the depreciation rate.

From the first-order condition with respect to capital, the firm’s inverse demand for capital is

(54.1)#\[r = A \alpha \left( \frac{N}{K} \right)^{1 - \alpha} - \delta\]

Using this expression and the firm’s first-order condition for labor, we can pin down the equilibrium wage rate as a function of \(r\) as

(54.2)#\[w(r) = A (1 - \alpha) (A \alpha / (r + \delta))^{\alpha / (1 - \alpha)}\]

54.3.1. Equilibrium#

We construct a stationary rational expectations equilibrium (SREE).

In such an equilibrium

  • prices induce behavior that generates aggregate quantities consistent with the prices

  • aggregate quantities and prices are constant over time

In more detail, an SREE lists a set of prices, savings and production policies such that

  • households want to choose the specified savings policies taking the prices as given

  • firms maximize profits taking the same prices as given

  • the resulting aggregate quantities are consistent with the prices; in particular, the demand for capital equals the supply

  • aggregate quantities (defined as cross-sectional averages) are constant

In practice, once parameter values are set, we can check for an SREE by the following steps

  1. pick a proposed quantity \(K\) for aggregate capital

  2. determine corresponding prices, with interest rate \(r\) determined by (54.1) and a wage rate \(w(r)\) as given in (54.2)

  3. determine the common optimal savings policy of the households given these prices

  4. compute aggregate capital as the mean of steady state capital given this savings policy

If this final quantity agrees with \(K\) then we have a SREE.

54.4. Code#

Let’s look at how we might compute such an equilibrium in practice.

To solve the household’s dynamic programming problem we’ll use the DiscreteDP type from QuantEcon.jl.

Our first task is the least exciting one: write code that maps parameters for a household problem into the R and Q matrices needed to generate an instance of DiscreteDP.

Below is a piece of boilerplate code that does just this.

In reading the code, the following information will be helpful

  • R needs to be a matrix where R[s, a] is the reward at state s under action a.

  • Q needs to be a three dimensional array where Q[s, a, s'] is the probability of transitioning to state s' when the current state is s and the current action is a.

(For a detailed discussion of DiscreteDP see this lecture)

Here we take the state to be \(s_t := (a_t, z_t)\), where \(a_t\) is assets and \(z_t\) is the shock.

The action is the choice of next period asset level \(a_{t+1}\).

The object also includes a default set of parameters that we’ll adopt unless otherwise specified.

using LinearAlgebra, Statistics
using LaTeXStrings, Plots, QuantEcon
function Household(; r = 0.01,
                   w = 1.0,
                   sigma = 1.0,
                   beta = 0.96,
                   z_chain = MarkovChain([0.9 0.1; 0.1 0.9], [0.1; 1.0]),
                   a_min = 1e-10,
                   a_max = 18.0,
                   a_size = 200,
                   a_vals = range(a_min, a_max, length = a_size),
                   # -Inf is the utility of dying (0 consumption)
                   u = sigma == 1 ? x -> log(x) :
                       x -> (x^(1 - sigma) - 1) / (1 - sigma))

    # Create grids
    z_size = length(z_chain.state_values)
    n = a_size * z_size
    s_vals = gridmake(a_vals, z_chain.state_values)
    s_i_vals = gridmake(1:a_size, 1:z_size)

    # Fill in the Q and R
    Q = zeros(n, a_size, n)
    for next_s_i in 1:size(Q, 3)
        for a_i in 1:size(Q, 2)
            for s_i in 1:size(Q, 1)
                z_i = s_i_vals[s_i, 2]
                next_z_i = s_i_vals[next_s_i, 2]
                next_a_i = s_i_vals[next_s_i, 1]
                if next_a_i == a_i
                    Q[s_i, a_i, next_s_i] = z_chain.p[z_i, next_z_i]
                end
            end
        end
    end

    R = fill(-Inf, n, a_size)
    for new_a_i in 1:size(R, 2)
        a_new = a_vals[new_a_i]
        for s_i in 1:size(R, 1)
            a = s_vals[s_i, 1]
            z = s_vals[s_i, 2]
            c = w * z + (1 + r) * a - a_new
            if c > 0
                R[s_i, new_a_i] = u(c)
            end
        end
    end
    return (; r, w, sigma, beta, z_chain, a_min, a_max, a_size, a_vals, z_size,
            n, s_vals, s_i_vals, u, R, Q)
end
Household (generic function with 1 method)

As a first example of what we can do, let’s compute and plot an optimal accumulation policy at fixed prices

# Create an instance of Household
am = Household(; a_max = 20.0, r = 0.03, w = 0.956)

# Use the instance to build a discrete dynamic program
am_ddp = DiscreteDP(am.R, am.Q, am.beta)

# Solve using policy function iteration
results = solve(am_ddp, PFI)

# Simplify names
(; z_size, a_size, n, a_vals) = am
z_vals = am.z_chain.state_values

# Get all optimal actions across the set of
# a indices with z fixed in each column
a_star = reshape([a_vals[results.sigma[s_i]] for s_i in 1:n], a_size, z_size)

labels = [L"z = %$(z_vals[1])" L"z = %$(z_vals[2])"]
plot(a_vals, a_star, label = labels, lw = 2, alpha = 0.6)
plot!(a_vals, a_vals, label = "", color = :black, linestyle = :dash)
plot!(xlabel = "current assets", ylabel = "next period assets", grid = false)

The plot shows asset accumulation policies at different values of the exogenous state.

Now we want to calculate the equilibrium.

Let’s do this visually as a first pass.

The following code draws aggregate supply and demand curves.

The intersection gives equilibrium interest rates and capital

# Calculate supply of capital for a given r
function prices_to_capital_stock(r; beta, A, N, alpha, delta, a_max)
    # Create an instance of Household given the parameters

    # Calculate the equilibrium wages
    w = A * (1 - alpha) * (A * alpha / (r + delta))^(alpha / (1 - alpha))
    am = Household(; beta, a_max, w, r)

    aiyagari_ddp = DiscreteDP(am.R, am.Q, am.beta)

    # Compute the optimal policy
    results = solve(aiyagari_ddp, PFI)

    # Compute the stationary distribution
    stationary_probs = stationary_distributions(results.mc)[:, 1][1]

    # Return K
    K = dot(am.s_vals[:, 1], stationary_probs)

    # Return capital
    return K
end

# Inverse Demand for capital
function r_inverse_demand(K; A, N, alpha, delta)
    return A * alpha * (N / K)^(1 - alpha) - delta
end

# Create a grid of r values at which to compute demand and supply of capital
r_vals = range(0.005, 0.04, length = 20)

# Firms' parameters
A = 1
N = 1
alpha = 0.33
beta = 0.96
delta = 0.05
a_max = 20.0

prices_to_capital_stock(r_vals[1]; A, N, alpha, beta, delta, a_max)

# Compute supply of capital
k_vals = prices_to_capital_stock.(r_vals; A, N, alpha, beta, delta, a_max)

r_inverse_demand_vals = r_inverse_demand.(k_vals; A, N, alpha, delta)

# Plot against demand for capital by firms
labels = ["demand for capital" "supply of capital"]
plot(k_vals, [r_inverse_demand_vals r_vals], label = labels, lw = 2,
     alpha = 0.6)
plot!(xlabel = "capital", ylabel = "interest rate", xlim = (2, 14),
      ylim = (0.0, 0.1))