63. Dynamic Stackelberg Problems#
Contents
This notebook formulates and computes a plan that a Stackelberg leader uses to manipulate forward-looking decisions of a Stackelberg follower that depend on continuation sequences of decisions made once and for all by the Stackelberg leader at time \(0\).
To facilitate computation and interpretation, we formulate things in a context that allows us to apply linear optimal dynamic programming.
From the beginning we carry along a linear-quadratic model of duopoly in which firms face adjustment costs that make them want to forecast actions of other firms that influence future prices.
63.1. Duopoly#
Time is discrete and is indexed by \(t = 0, 1, \ldots\).
Two firms produce a single good whose demand is governed by the linear inverse demand curve
where \(q_{it}\) is output of firm \(i\) at time \(t\) and \(a_0\) and \(a_1\) are both positive.
\(q_{10}, q_{20}\) are given numbers that serve as initial conditions at time \(0\).
By incurring a cost of change
where \(\gamma > 0\), firm \(i\) can change its output according to
Firm \(i\)’s profits at time \(t\) equal
Firm \(i\) wants to maximize the present value of its profits
where \(\beta \in (0,1)\) is a time discount factor.
63.1.1. Stackelberg Leader and Follower#
Each firm \(i=1,2\) chooses a sequence \(\vec q_i \equiv \{q_{it+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all at time \(0\).
We let firm 2 be a Stackelberg leader and firm 1 be a Stackelberg follower.
The leader firm 2 goes first and chooses \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all at time \(0\).
Knowing that firm 2 has chosen \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\), the follower firm 1 goes second and chooses \(\{q_{1t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all at time \(0\).
In choosing \(\vec q_2\), firm 2 takes into account that firm 1 will base its choice of \(\vec q_1\) on firm 2’s choice of \(\vec q_2\).
63.1.2. Abstract Statement of the Leader’s and Follower’s Problems#
We can express firm 1’s problem as
where the appearance behind the semi-colon indicates that \(\vec q_2\) is given.
Firm 1’s problem induces a best response mapping
(Here \(B\) maps a sequence into a sequence)
The Stackelberg leader’s problem is
whose maximizer is a sequence \(\vec q_2\) that depends on the initial conditions \(q_{10}, q_{20}\) and the parameters of the model \(a_0, a_1, \gamma\).
This formulation captures key features of the model
Both firms make once-and-for-all choices at time \(0\).
This is true even though both firms are choosing sequences of quantities that are indexed by time.
The Stackelberg leader chooses first within time \(0\), knowing that the Stackelberg follower will choose second within time \(0\).
While our abstract formulation reveals the timing protocol and equilibrium concept well, it obscures details that must be addressed when we want to compute and interpret a Stackelberg plan and the follower’s best response to it.
To gain insights about these things, we study them in more detail.
63.1.3. Firms’ Problems#
Firm 1 acts as if firm 2’s sequence \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) is given and beyond its control.
Firm 2 knows that firm 1 chooses second and takes this into account in choosing \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\).
In the spirit of working backwards, we study firm 1’s problem first, taking \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) as given.
We can formulate firm 1’s optimum problem in terms of the Lagrangian
Firm 1 seeks a maximum with respect to \(\{q_{1t+1}, v_{1t} \}_{t=0}^\infty\) and a minimum with respect to \(\{ \lambda_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\).
We approach this problem using methods described in Ljungqvist and Sargent RMT5 chapter 2, appendix A and Macroeconomic Theory, 2nd edition, chapter IX.
First-order conditions for this problem are
These first-order conditions and the constraint \(q_{1t+1} = q_{1t} + v_{1t}\) can be rearranged to take the form
We can substitute the second equation into the first equation to obtain
where \(c_0 = \frac{\beta a_0}{2 \gamma}, c_1 = \frac{\beta a_1}{\gamma}, c_2 = \frac{\beta a_1}{2 \gamma}\).
This equation can in turn be rearranged to become the second-order difference equation
Equation (63.1) is a second-order difference equation in the sequence \(\vec q_1\) whose solution we want.
It satisfies two boundary conditions:
an initial condition that \(q_{1,0}\), which is given
a terminal condition requiring that \(\lim_{T \rightarrow + \infty} \beta^T q_{1t}^2 < + \infty\)
Using the lag operators described in chapter IX of Macroeconomic Theory, Second edition (1987), difference equation (63.1) can be written as
The polynomial in the lag operator on the left side can be factored as
where \(0 < \delta_1 < 1 < \frac{1}{\sqrt{\beta}} < \delta_2\).
Because \(\delta_2 > \frac{1}{\sqrt{\beta}}\) the operator \((1 - \delta_2 L)\) contributes an unstable component if solved backwards but a stable component if solved forwards.
Mechanically, write
and compute the following inverse operator
Operating on both sides of equation (63.2) with \(\beta^{-1}\) times this inverse operator gives the follower’s decision rule for setting \(q_{1t+1}\) in the feedback-feedforward form
The problem of the Stackelberg leader firm 2 is to choose the sequence \(\{q_{2t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) to maximize its discounted profits
subject to the sequence of constraints (63.3) for \(t \geq 0\).
We can put a sequence \(\{\theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) of Lagrange multipliers on the sequence of equations (63.3) and formulate the following Lagrangian for the Stackelberg leader firm 2’s problem
subject to initial conditions for \(q_{1t}, q_{2t}\) at \(t=0\).
Comments: We have formulated the Stackelberg problem in a space of sequences.
The max-min problem associated with Lagrangian (63.4) is unpleasant because the time \(t\) component of firm \(1\)’s payoff function depends on the entire future of its choices of \(\{q_{1t+j}\}_{j=0}^\infty\).
This renders a direct attack on the problem cumbersome.
Therefore, below, we will formulate the Stackelberg leader’s problem recursively.
We’ll put our little duopoly model into a broader class of models with the same conceptual structure.
63.2. The Stackelberg Problem#
We formulate a class of linear-quadratic Stackelberg leader-follower problems of which our duopoly model is an instance.
We use the optimal linear regulator (a.k.a. the linear-quadratic dynamic programming problem described in LQ Dynamic Programming problems) to represent a Stackelberg leader’s problem recursively.
Let \(z_t\) be an \(n_z \times 1\) vector of natural state variables.
Let \(x_t\) be an \(n_x \times 1\) vector of endogenous forward-looking variables that are physically free to jump at \(t\).
In our duopoly example \(x_t = v_{1t}\), the time \(t\) decision of the Stackelberg follower.
Let \(u_t\) be a vector of decisions chosen by the Stackelberg leader at \(t\).
The \(z_t\) vector is inherited physically from the past.
But \(x_t\) is a decision made by the Stackelberg follower at time \(t\) that is the follower’s best response to the choice of an entire sequence of decisions made by the Stackelberg leader at time \(t=0\).
Let
Represent the Stackelberg leader’s one-period loss function as
Subject to an initial condition for \(z_0\), but not for \(x_0\), the Stackelberg leader wants to maximize
The Stackelberg leader faces the model
We assume that the matrix \(\begin{bmatrix} I & 0 \\ G_{21} & G_{22} \end{bmatrix}\) on the left side of equation (63.6) is invertible, so that we can multiply both sides by its inverse to obtain
or
63.2.1. Interpretation of the Second Block of Equations#
The Stackelberg follower’s best response mapping is summarized by the second block of equations of (63.7).
In particular, these equations are the first-order conditions of the Stackelberg follower’s optimization problem (i.e., its Euler equations).
These Euler equations summarize the forward-looking aspect of the follower’s behavior and express how its time \(t\) decision depends on the leader’s actions at times \(s \geq t\).
When combined with a stability condition to be imposed below, the Euler equations summarize the follower’s best response to the sequence of actions by the leader.
The Stackelberg leader maximizes (63.5) by choosing sequences \(\{u_t, x_t, z_{t+1}\}_{t=0}^{\infty}\) subject to (63.8) and an initial condition for \(z_0\).
Note that we have an initial condition for \(z_0\) but not for \(x_0\).
\(x_0\) is among the variables to be chosen at time \(0\) by the Stackelberg leader.
The Stackelberg leader uses its understanding of the responses restricted by (63.8) to manipulate the follower’s decisions.
63.2.2. More Mechanical Details#
For any vector \(a_t\), define \(\vec a_t = [a_t, a_{t+1} \ldots ]\).
Define a feasible set of \((\vec y_1, \vec u_0)\) sequences
Please remember that the follower’s Euler equation is embedded in the system of dynamic equations \(y_{t+1} = A y_t + B u_t\).
Note that in the definition of \(\Omega(y_0)\), \(y_0\) is taken as given.
Although it is taken as given in \(\Omega(y_0)\), eventually, the \(x_0\) component of \(y_0\) will be chosen by the Stackelberg leader.
63.2.3. Two Subproblems#
Once again we use backward induction.
We express the Stackelberg problem in terms of two subproblems.
Subproblem 1 is solved by a continuation Stackelberg leader at each date \(t \geq 0\).
Subproblem 2 is solved the Stackelberg leader at \(t=0\).
The two subproblems are designed
to respect the protocol in which the follower chooses \(\vec q_1\) after seeing \(\vec q_2\) chosen by the leader
to make the leader choose \(\vec q_2\) while respecting that \(\vec q_1\) will be the follower’s best response to \(\vec q_2\)
to represent the leader’s problem recursively by artfully choosing the state variables confronting and the control variables available to the leader
63.2.3.1. Subproblem 1#
63.2.3.2. Subproblem 2#
Subproblem 1 takes the vector of forward-looking variables \(x_0\) as given.
Subproblem 2 optimizes over \(x_0\).
The value function \(w(z_0)\) tells the value of the Stackelberg plan as a function of the vector of natural state variables at time \(0\), \(z_0\).
63.2.4. Two Bellman Equations#
We now describe Bellman equations for \(v(y)\) and \(w(z_0)\).
63.2.4.1. Subproblem 1#
The value function \(v(y)\) in subproblem 1 satisfies the Bellman equation
where the maximization is subject to
and \(y^*\) denotes next period’s value.
Substituting \(v(y) = - y'P y\) into Bellman equation (63.9) gives
which as in lecture linear regulator gives rise to the algebraic matrix Riccati equation
and the optimal decision rule coefficient vector
where the optimal decision rule is
63.2.4.2. Subproblem 2#
We find an optimal \(x_0\) by equating to zero the gradient of \(v(y_0)\) with respect to \(x_0\):
which implies that
63.3. Stackelberg Plan#
Now let’s map our duopoly model into the above setup.
We we’ll formulate a state space system
where in this instance \(x_t = v_{1t}\), the time \(t\) decision of the follower firm 1.
63.3.1. Calculations to Prepare Duopoly Model#
Now we’ll proceed to cast our duopoly model within the framework of the more general linear-quadratic structure described above.
That will allow us to compute a Stackelberg plan simply by enlisting a Riccati equation to solve a linear-quadratic dynamic program.
As emphasized above, firm 1 acts as if firm 2’s decisions \(\{q_{2t+1}, v_{2t}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) are given and beyond its control.
63.3.2. Firm 1’s Problem#
We again formulate firm 1’s optimum problem in terms of the Lagrangian
Firm 1 seeks a maximum with respect to \(\{q_{1t+1}, v_{1t} \}_{t=0}^\infty\) and a minimum with respect to \(\{ \lambda_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\).
First-order conditions for this problem are
These first-order order conditions and the constraint \(q_{1t+1} = q_{1t} + v_{1t}\) can be rearranged to take the form
We use these two equations as components of the following linear system that confronts a Stackelberg continuation leader at time \(t\)
Time \(t\) revenues of firm 2 are \(\pi_{2t} = a_0 q_{2t} - a_1 q_{2t}^2 - a_1 q_{1t} q_{2t}\) which evidently equal
If we set \(Q = \gamma\), then firm 2’s period \(t\) profits can then be written
where
with \(x_t = v_{1t}\) and
We’ll report results of implementing this code soon.
But first we want to represent the Stackelberg leader’s optimal choices recursively.
It is important to do this for several reasons:
properly to interpret a representation of the Stackelberg leaders’s choice as a sequence of history-dependent functions
to formulate a recursive version of the follower’s choice problem
First let’s get a recursive representation of the Stackelberg leader’s choice of \(\vec q_2\) for our duopoly model.
63.4. Recursive Representation of Stackelberg Plan#
In order to attain an appropriate representation of the Stackelberg leader’s history-dependent plan, we will employ what amounts to a version of the Big K, little k device often used in macroeconomics by distinguishing \(z_t\), which depends partly on decisions \(x_t\) of the followers, from another vector \(\check z_t\), which does not.
We will use \(\check z_t\) and its history \(\check z^t = [\check z_t, \check z_{t-1}, \ldots, \check z_0]\) to describe the sequence of the Stackelberg leader’s decisions that the Stackelberg follower takes as given.
Thus, we let \(\check y_t' = \begin{bmatrix}\check z_t' & \check x_t'\end{bmatrix}\) with initial condition \(\check z_0 = z_0\) given.
That we distinguish \(\check z_t\) from \(z_t\) is part and parcel of the Big K, little k device in this instance.
We have demonstrated that a Stackelberg plan for \(\{u_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) has a recursive representation
From this representation we can deduce the sequence of functions \(\sigma = \{\sigma_t(\check z^t)\}_{t=0}^\infty\) that comprise a Stackelberg plan.
For convenience, let \(\check A \equiv A - BF\) and partition \(\check A\) conformably to the partition \(y_t = \begin{bmatrix}\check z_t \cr \check x_t \end{bmatrix}\) as
Let \(H^0_0 \equiv - P_{22}^{-1} P_{21}\) so that \(\check x_0 = H^0_0 \check z_0\).
Then iterations on \(\check y_{t+1} = \check A \check y_t\) starting from initial condition \(\check y_0 = \begin{bmatrix}\check z_0 \cr H^0_0 \check z_0\end{bmatrix}\) imply that for \(t \geq 1\)
where
An optimal decision rule for the Stackelberg’s choice of \(u_t\) is
or
Representation (63.10) confirms that whenever \(F_x \neq 0\), the typical situation, the time \(t\) component \(\sigma_t\) of a Stackelberg plan is history dependent, meaning that the Stackelberg leader’s choice \(u_t\) depends not just on \(\check z_t\) but on components of \(\check z^{t-1}\).
63.4.2. Dynamic Programming and Time Consistency of follower’s Problem#
Given the sequence \(\vec q_2\) chosen by the Stackelberg leader in our duopoly model, it turns out that the Stackelberg follower’s problem is recursive in the natural state variables that confront a follower at any time \(t \geq 0\).
This means that the follower’s plan is time consistent.
To verify these claims, we’ll formulate a recursive version of a follower’s problem that builds on our recursive representation of the Stackelberg leader’s plan and our use of the Big K, little k idea.
63.4.3. Recursive Formulation of a Follower’s Problem#
We now use what amounts to another “Big \(K\), little \(k\)” trick (see rational expectations equilibrium) to formulate a recursive version of a follower’s problem cast in terms of an ordinary Bellman equation.
Firm 1, the follower, faces \(\{q_{2t}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) as a given quantity sequence chosen by the leader and believes that its output price at \(t\) satisfies
Our challenge is to represent \(\{q_{2t}\}_{t=0}^\infty\) as a given sequence.
To do so, recall that under the Stackelberg plan, firm 2 sets output according to the \(q_{2t}\) component of
which is governed by
To obtain a recursive representation of a \(\{q_{2t}\}\) sequence that is exogenous to firm 1, we define a state \(\tilde y_t\)
that evolves according to
subject to the initial condition \(\tilde q_{10} = q_{10}\) and \(\tilde x_0 = x_0\) where \(x_0 = - P_{22}^{-1} P_{21}\) as stated above.
Firm 1’s state vector is
It follows that the follower firm 1 faces law of motion
This specfification assures that from the point of the view of a firm 1, \(q_{2t}\) is an exogenous process.
Here
\(\tilde q_{1t}, \tilde x_t\) play the role of Big K.
\(q_{1t}, x_t\) play the role of little k.
The time \(t\) component of firm 1’s objective is
Firm 1’s optimal decision rule is
and it’s state evolves according to
under its optimal decision rule.
Later we shall compute \(\tilde F\) and verify that when we set
we recover
which will verify that we have properly set up a recursive representation of the follower’s problem facing the Stackelberg leader’s \(\vec q_2\).
63.4.4. Time Consistency of Follower’s Plan#
Since the follower can solve its problem using dynamic programming its problem is recursive in what for it are the natural state variables, namely
It follows that the follower’s plan is time consistent.
63.5. Computing the Stackelberg Plan#
Here is our code to compute a Stackelberg plan via a linear-quadratic dynamic program as outlined above
using LaTeXStrings, QuantEcon, Plots, LinearAlgebra, Statistics,
Random
We define named tuples and default values for the model and solver settings, and instantiate one copy of each
function model(; a0 = 10, a1 = 2, beta = 0.96, gamma = 120.0, n = 300)
return (; a0, a1, beta, gamma, n)
end
# things like tolerances, etc.
settings(; tol0 = 1e-8, tol1 = 1e-16, tol2 = 1e-2) = (; tol0, tol1, tol2)
defaultModel = model();
defaultSettings = settings();
Now we can compute the actual policy using the LQ routine from QuantEcon.jl
(; a0, a1, beta, gamma, n) = defaultModel
(; tol0, tol1, tol2) = defaultSettings
betas = [beta^x for x in 0:(n - 1)]
Alhs = I + zeros(4, 4);
Alhs[4, :] = [
beta * a0 / (2 * gamma),
-beta * a1 / (2 * gamma),
-beta * a1 / gamma,
beta,
] # Euler equation coefficients
Arhs = I + zeros(4, 4);
Arhs[3, 4] = 1.0;
Alhsinv = inv(Alhs);
A = Alhsinv * Arhs;
B = Alhsinv * [0, 1, 0, 0];
R = [0 -a0/2 0 0; -a0/2 a1 a1/2 0; 0 a1/2 0 0; 0 0 0 0];
Q = gamma;
lq = QuantEcon.LQ(Q, R, A, B, bet = beta);
P, F, d = stationary_values(lq)
P22 = P[4:end, 4:end];
P21 = P[4:end, 1:3];
P22inv = inv(P22);
H_0_0 = -P22inv * P21;
# simulate forward
pi_leader = zeros(n);
z0 = [1, 1, 1];
x0 = H_0_0 * z0;
y0 = vcat(z0, x0);
Random.seed!(1) # for reproducibility
yt, ut = compute_sequence(lq, y0, n);
pi_matrix = R + F' * Q * F;
for t in 1:n
pi_leader[t] = -(yt[:, t]' * pi_matrix * yt[:, t])
end
println("Computed policy for Stackelberg leader: $F")
Computed policy for Stackelberg leader: [-1.580044538772656 0.294613127470314 0.6748093760774967 6.539705936147509]
63.5.1. Implied Time Series for Price and Quantities#
The following code plots the price and quantities
q_leader = yt[2, 1:end];
q_follower = yt[3, 1:end];
q = q_leader + q_follower;
p = a0 .- a1 * q;
plot(1:(n + 1), [q_leader, q_follower, p],
title = "Output and Prices, Stackelberg Duopoly",
labels = ["leader output" "follower output" "price"],
xlabel = L"t")
63.5.2. Value of Stackelberg Leader#
We’ll compute the present value earned by the Stackelberg leader.
We’ll compute it two ways (they give identical answers – just a check on coding and thinking)
v_leader_forward = sum(betas .* pi_leader);
v_leader_direct = -yt[:, 1]' * P * yt[:, 1];
println("v_leader_forward (forward sim) is $v_leader_forward")
println("v_leader_direct is $v_leader_direct")
v_leader_forward (forward sim) is 150.03162125325494
v_leader_direct is 150.03237147549044
# manually check whether P is an approximate fixed point
P_next = (R + F' * Q * F + beta * (A - B * F)' * P * (A - B * F));
all(P - P_next .< tol0)
true
# manually checks whether two different ways of computing the
# value function give approximately the same answer
v_expanded = -((y0' * R * y0 + ut[:, 1]' * Q * ut[:, 1] +
beta * (y0' * (A - B * F)' * P * (A - B * F) * y0)));
(v_leader_direct - v_expanded < tol0)[1, 1]
true
63.6. Exhibiting Time Inconsistency of Stackelberg Plan#
In the code below we compare two values
the continuation value \(- y_t P y_t\) earned by a continuation Stackelberg leader who inherits state \(y_t\) at \(t\)
the value of a reborn Stackelberg leader who inherits state \(z_t\) at \(t\) and sets \(x_t = - P_{22}^{-1} P_{21}\)
The difference between these two values is a tell-tale time of the time inconsistency of the Stackelberg plan
# Compute value function over time with reset at time t
vt_leader = zeros(n);
vt_reset_leader = similar(vt_leader);
yt_reset = copy(yt)
yt_reset[end, :] = (H_0_0 * yt[1:3, :])
for t in 1:n
vt_leader[t] = -yt[:, t]' * P * yt[:, t]
vt_reset_leader[t] = -yt_reset[:, t]' * P * yt_reset[:, t]
end
p1 = plot(1:(n + 1), [(-F * yt)', (-F * yt_reset)'],
labels = ["Stackelberg Leader" L"Continuation Leader at $t$"],
title = "Leader Control Variable", xlabel = L"t");
p2 = plot(1:(n + 1), [yt[4, :], yt_reset[4, :]],
title = "Follower Control Variable", xlabel = L"t", legend = false);
p3 = plot(1:n, [vt_leader, vt_reset_leader], legend = false,
xlabel = L"t", title = "Leader Value Function");
plot(p1, p2, p3, layout = (3, 1), size = (800, 600))
63.7. Recursive Formulation of the Follower’s Problem#
We now formulate and compute the recursive version of the follower’s problem.
We check that the recursive Big \(K\) , little \(k\) formulation of the follower’s problem produces the same output path \(\vec q_1\) that we computed when we solved the Stackelberg problem
A_tilde = I + zeros(5, 5);
A_tilde[1:4, 1:4] .= A - B * F;
R_tilde = [0 0 0 0 -a0/2; 0 0 0 0 a1/2; 0 0 0 0 0; 0 0 0 0 0; -a0/2 a1/2 0 0 a1];
Q_tilde = Q;
B_tilde = [0, 0, 0, 0, 1];
lq_tilde = QuantEcon.LQ(Q_tilde, R_tilde, A_tilde, B_tilde, bet = beta);
P_tilde, F_tilde, d_tilde = stationary_values(lq_tilde);
y0_tilde = vcat(y0, y0[3]);
yt_tilde = compute_sequence(lq_tilde, y0_tilde, n)[1];
# checks that the recursive formulation of the follower's problem gives
# the same solution as the original Stackelberg problem
plot(1:(n + 1), [yt_tilde[5, :], yt_tilde[3, :]], labels = [L"\tilde{q}" L"q"])
Note: Variables with _tilde
are obtained from solving the follower’s
problem – those without are from the Stackelberg problem.
# maximum absolute difference in quantities over time between the first and second solution methods
max(abs(yt_tilde[5] - yt_tilde[3]))
0.0
# x0 == x0_tilde
yt[:, 1][end] - (yt_tilde[:, 2] - yt_tilde[:, 1])[end] < tol0
true
63.7.1. Explanation of Alignment#
If we inspect the coefficients in the decision rule \(- \tilde F\), we can spot the reason that the follower chooses to set \(x_t = \tilde x_t\) when it sets \(x_t = - \tilde F X_t\) in the recursive formulation of the follower problem.
Can you spot what features of \(\tilde F\) imply this?
Hint: remember the components of \(X_t\)
F_tilde # policy function in the follower's problem
1×5 Matrix{Float64}:
-5.73502e-17 -2.38959e-18 -0.103187 -1.0 0.103187
P # value function in the Stackelberg problem
4×4 Matrix{Float64}:
963.541 -194.605 -511.622 -5258.23
-194.605 37.3536 81.9771 784.765
-511.622 81.9771 247.343 2517.05
-5258.23 784.765 2517.05 25556.2
P_tilde # value function in the follower's problem
5×5 Matrix{Float64}:
-18.1991 2.58003 15.6049 151.23 -5.0
2.58003 -0.969466 -5.26008 -50.9764 1.0
15.6049 -5.26008 -32.2759 -312.792 -12.3824
151.23 -50.9764 -312.792 -3031.33 -120.0
-5.0 1.0 -12.3824 -120.0 14.3824
# manually check that P is an approximate fixed point
all((P - ((R + F' * Q * F) + beta * (A - B * F)' * P * (A - B * F)) .< tol0))
true
# compute `P_guess` using `F_tilde_star`
F_tilde_star = -[0, 0, 0, 1, 0]';
P_guess = zeros(5, 5);
for i in 1:1000
P_guess = ((R_tilde + F_tilde_star' * Q_tilde * F_tilde_star) +
beta * (A_tilde - B_tilde * F_tilde_star)' * P_guess
* (A_tilde - B_tilde * F_tilde_star))
end
# value function in the follower's problem
-(y0_tilde' * P_tilde * y0_tilde)[1, 1]
112.655907405782
# value function using P_guess
-(y0_tilde' * P_guess * y0_tilde)[1, 1]
112.65590740578187
# c policy using policy iteration algorithm
F_iter = (beta * inv(Q + beta * B_tilde' * P_guess * B_tilde)
* B_tilde' * P_guess * A_tilde);
P_iter = zeros(5, 5);
dist_vec = zeros(5, 5);
for i in 1:100
# compute P_iter
dist_vec = similar(P_iter)
for j in 1:1000
P_iter = (R_tilde + F_iter' * Q * F_iter) +
beta *
(A_tilde - B_tilde * F_iter)' * P_iter *
(A_tilde - B_tilde * F_iter)
# update F_iter
F_iter = beta * inv(Q + beta * B_tilde' * P_iter * B_tilde) *
B_tilde' * P_iter * A_tilde
dist_vec = P_iter - ((R_tilde + F_iter' * Q * F_iter) +
beta * (A_tilde - B_tilde * F_iter)' * P_iter *
(A_tilde - B_tilde * F_iter))
end
end
if maximum(abs.(dist_vec)) < 1e-8
dist_vec2 = F_iter -
(beta * inv(Q + beta * B_tilde' * P_iter * B_tilde) * B_tilde' *
P_iter * A_tilde)
if maximum(abs.(dist_vec2)) < 1e-8
@show F_iter
else
println("The policy didn't converge: try increasing the number of outer loop iterations")
end
else
println("The policy didn't converge: try increasing the number of inner loop iterations")
end
F_iter = [4.85722573273506e-17 -1.9949319973733282e-17 -0.10318650145223833 -1.000000000000001 0.1031865014522382]
1×5 adjoint(::Vector{Float64}) with eltype Float64:
4.85723e-17 -1.99493e-17 -0.103187 -1.0 0.103187
yt_tilde_star = zeros(n, 5);
yt_tilde_star[1, :] = y0_tilde;
for t in 1:(n - 1)
yt_tilde_star[t + 1, :] = (A_tilde - B_tilde * F_tilde_star) *
yt_tilde_star[t, :]
end
plot([yt_tilde_star[:, 5], yt_tilde[3, :]], labels = [L"\tilde{q}" L"q"])
maximum(abs.(yt_tilde_star[:, 5] - yt_tilde[3, 1:(end - 1)]))
0.0
63.8. Markov Perfect Equilibrium#
The state vector is
and the state transition dynamics are
where \(A\) is a \(3 \times 3\) identity matrix and
The Markov perfect decision rules are
and in the Markov perfect equilibrium the state evolves according to
# in LQ form
A = I + zeros(3, 3);
B1 = [0, 0, 1];
B2 = [0, 1, 0];
R1 = [0 0 -a0/2; 0 0 a1/2; -a0/2 a1/2 a1];
R2 = [0 -a0/2 0; -a0/2 a1 a1/2; 0 a1/2 0];
Q1 = Q2 = gamma;
S1 = S2 = W1 = W2 = M1 = M2 = 0.0;
# solve using nnash from QE
F1, F2, P1, P2 = nnash(A, B1, B2, R1, R2, Q1, Q2,
S1, S2, W1, W2, M1, M2,
beta = beta,
tol = tol1);
# simulate forward
AF = A - B1 * F1 - B2 * F2;
z = zeros(3, n);
z[:, 1] .= 1;
for t in 1:(n - 1)
z[:, t + 1] = AF * z[:, t]
end
println("Policy for F1 is $F1")
println("Policy for F2 is $F2")
Policy for F1 is [-0.22701362843207126 0.03129874118441059 0.09447112842804818]
Policy for F2 is [-0.22701362843207126 0.09447112842804818 0.03129874118441059]
q1 = z[2, :];
q2 = z[3, :];
q = q1 + q2; # total output, MPE
p = a0 .- a1 * q; # total price, MPE
plot([q, p], labels = ["total ouput" "total price"],
title = "Output and prices, duopoly MPE", xlabel = L"t")
# computes the maximum difference in quantities across firms
maximum(abs.(q1 - q2))
1.9984014443252818e-15
# compute values
u1 = -F1 * z;
u2 = -F2 * z;
pi_1 = (p .* q1)' - gamma * u1 .^ 2;
pi_2 = (p .* q2)' - gamma * u2 .^ 2;
v1_forward = pi_1 * betas;
v2_forward = pi_2 * betas;
v1_direct = -z[:, 1]' * P1 * z[:, 1];
v2_direct = -z[:, 1]' * P2 * z[:, 1];
println("Firm 1: Direct is $v1_direct, Forward is $(v1_forward[1])");
println("Firm 2: Direct is $v2_direct, Forward is $(v2_forward[1])");
Firm 1: Direct is 133.32949812474203, Forward is 133.33033197956638
Firm 2: Direct is 133.32949812474203, Forward is 133.3303319795664
# sanity check
Lambda_1 = A - B2 * F2;
lq1 = QuantEcon.LQ(Q1, R1, Lambda_1, B1, bet = beta);
P1_ih, F1_ih, d = stationary_values(lq1);
v2_direct_alt = -z[:, 1]' * P1_ih * z[:, 1] + d;
all(abs.(v2_direct - v2_direct_alt) < tol2)
true
63.9. MPE vs. Stackelberg#
vt_MPE = zeros(n);
vt_follower = zeros(n);
for t in 1:n
vt_MPE[t] = -z[:, t]' * P1 * z[:, t]
vt_follower[t] = -yt_tilde[:, t]' * P_tilde * yt_tilde[:, t]
end
plot([vt_MPE, vt_leader, vt_follower],
labels = ["MPE" "Stackelberg leader" "Stackelberg follower"],
title = "MPE vs Stackelberg Values",
xlabel = L"t",
legend = :outertopright)
# display values
println("vt_leader(y0) = $(vt_leader[1])");
println("vt_follower(y0) = $(vt_follower[1])")
println("vt_MPE(y0) = $(vt_MPE[1])");
vt_leader(y0) = 150.03237147549044
vt_follower(y0) = 112.655907405782
vt_MPE(y0) = 133.32949812474203
# total difference in value b/t Stackelberg and MPE
vt_leader[1] + vt_follower[1] - 2 * vt_MPE[1]
-3.9707173682116377
63.4.1. Comments and Interpretations#
After all, at the end of the day, it will turn out that because we set \(\check z_0 = z_0\), it will be true that \(z_t = \check z_t\) for all \(t \geq 0\).
Then why did we distinguish \(\check z_t\) from \(z_t\)?
The answer is that if we want to present to the Stackelberg follower a history-dependent representation of the Stackelberg leader’s sequence \(\vec q_2\), we must use representation (63.10) cast in terms of the history \(\check z^t\) and not a corresponding representation cast in terms of \(z^t\).